Review of: Why Politics Fails: The Five Traps of the Modern World & How to Escape Them
Author: Ben Ansell
Publisher: Public Affairs, 2023
If one could pinpoint the apex of liberal democracy, perhaps Francis Fukuyama’s 1989 article The End of History wouldn’t be a bad place to start. With the fall of the Soviet Union, liberal democracy seemed unbeatable as a political system. It’s all been downhill for democracies ever since.
Over the last decade, many books have lamented the decline and fall of liberal democracies with remedies to save them, including Thomas Piketty’s Capital (2017) to the more recent The Crisis of Democratic Capitalism (2023) by Martin Wolf of The Financial Times. All acknowledged the dangers of rising income and wealth disparities, the decline of the middle class, and the rise of populism and authoritarianism.
We have another book, Why Politics Fails, by Professor Ben Ansell, who teaches political science at Oxford, on how our desires to do things fall short. We all want a democracy that reflects the will of the people and less wealth and income disparities. We crave more personal security and an economy that creates prosperity without endangering the planet. Unfortunately, we’re trapped between the rock of good intentions and the hard place of self-interest. Ansell argues there is a way out if we apply promising social and economic research findings and the political will to implement them. For example, liberal democracies swing between indecision and political polarization without representing the people’s true will. Ansell suggests improving democracy with more democracy. Countries with greater voter options, such as proportional representation, seem more successful than those without. But PR is a double-edged sword. And Italy is an example.
What about the problem of greater inequality as economies gravitate to extremes of wealth and income disparities? Here we have a clash between equal rights and equal outcomes. There’s no question that we need to transfer wealth to the least of us, but what works best? Ansell suggests designing programs convincing us that higher taxes, especially on the rich, are essential for social investments that benefit all. He believes we can tolerate higher marginal taxes in the 60-70 percent range before the desire of high-income earners to work and earn more slacks off. But it would be a brave political party to suggest taxes anywhere near those marginal rates.
To encourage greater social solidarity between citizens, we should turn to programs that have worked in the Scandinavian countries that provide universal social programs with generous childcare leave for both parents where the poor aren’t left at the mercy of the market. But transferring lessons from other countries isn’t easy and sometimes ill-advised. Countries have histories, cultures, and legal and political traditions that are deeply entrenched and hard to change. Europe hasn’t managed to create a Silicon Valley or Apple Inc., while the U.S. medical system seems almost unreformable.
On the issue of security, the author worries that giving too much power to the police and armed forces risks tipping us into tyranny. Tightly controlled societies repel innovation compared to open and free ones. Ansell is deeply critical of U.S. police action that led to the 2014 killing of Michael Brown in Ferguson, Missouri, and the riots that followed, without acknowledging the difficulty of keeping the peace in dangerous neighbourhoods. As some European nations have discovered, this problem isn’t restricted to American cities.
Finally, there’s the prosperity trap: we often sacrifice long-term gains for short-term profits. He says this is the same 16th-century attitude that led Europeans to exploit their colonies without consideration for the long-term consequences. This is a cursory reading of colonial history, but the lesson is clear. He thinks the Germans have found ways to encourage long-term business innovation with public funds. But Americans remain the world’s powerhouse of patent holders and scientific Nobel Prize winners. On the environment, Ansell seems to approve a straight carbon tax over other programs such as cap and trade or regulations on CO2 emissions. But it is disappointing that he doesn’t at least consider support for nuclear power and carbon sink technologies.
Undoubtedly, Professor Ansell knows his subject and the latest policy research, and his book Why Politics Fails has deep faith in the latest political and economic research. It’s not as if Professor Ansell is wrong, only that his solutions rely on a change in the hearts and minds of people, a tall order in any age. However, I do take issue with how he starts his book believing that the most pressing crisis is climate change. It’s not. The most important is the human condition.
He looks at policy from the perspective of 30,000 feet, but the nitty-gritty of policy happens on the ground, where the problems such as poverty and unemployment look much more difficult to solve. But knowledge and policies that look good today change tomorrow. Scientific facts of political economy are always in the state of discovery, which precludes judging any political solution as definitive. The recent riots throughout France reflect poorly on the vast sums spent over the decades on training, education, and anti-poverty programs designed, no doubt, by the world’s best political and economic thinkers.
Closer to home, Toronto’s new mayor-elect has promised to fix the housing shortage that has only deteriorated as the city grows and prospers. And no doubt she’ll rely on the best social science minds. At the end of her term, she’ll point to a few short-term successes, but we’ll be disappointed and start the process over again. Why do politics fail? Perhaps because some problems are beyond our capacity to solve.